Głowacki Law Firm

EU ETS cost/benefit analyses based on artificial and unrealistic assumptions - Page 2
Saturday, 16 February 2013 13:38

 

When it comes to details Guidance document No. 1 underlines that it is up to the operator to provide a reasonable estimation of the costs involved. Only costs which are additional to those applicable for the alternative scenario should be taken into account. The M&R Regulation also requires that the equipment costs are to be assessed using a depreciation period appropriate for the economic lifetime of the equipment. Thus, the annual costs during the lifetime rather than the total equipment costs are to be used in the assessment.

 

On the part of determining the assumed benefit, the allowance price is to be multiplied by an “improvement factor”, which is the improvement of uncertainty multiplied by the average annual emissions caused by the respective source stream over the three most recent years. The improvement of uncertainty is the difference between the uncertainty currently achieved.

 

Where no direct improvement of the accuracy of emissions data is achieved by an improvement, the improvement factor is always 1%. Article 18(3) lists some of such improvements, e.g. switching from default values to analyses, increasing the number of samples analysed, improving the data flow and control system, etc.

 

However, accumulated improvement costs below 2 000 € per year are always considered reasonable, without assessing the benefit. For installations with low emissions this threshold is only 500 €.

 

In order to make these theoretical remarks more illustrative it would be useful to refer to a practical example given by the above-mentioned Guidance document No. 1:

 

An old measuring instrument is found to not function properly any more, and is to be exchanged for a new one. The old instrument has allowed reaching an uncertainty of 3% corresponding to tier 2 (±5%) for activity data. Because the operator would have to apply a higher tier anyway, he considers whether a better instrument would incur unreasonable costs. Instrument A costs 40 000 € and leads to an uncertainty of 2.8% (still tier 2), instrument B costs 70 000 €, but allows an uncertainty of 2.1% (tier 3, ±2.5%). Due to the rough environment in the installation, a depreciation period of 5 years is considered appropriate.

 

The costs to be taken into account for the assessment of unreasonable costs are 30 000 € (i.e. the difference between the two meters) divided by 5 years, i.e. 6 000 €. No cost for the working time should be considered, as the same workload is assumed to be necessary independent from the type of the meter to be installed. Also same maintenance costs can be assumed as approximation.

 

For the replacement of meters, the benefit of “improvement” for instrument A is zero, as it is a mere replacement maintaining the current tier. It cannot be unreasonable, as the installation cannot be operated without at least this instrument.

 

In case of instrument B, tier 3 (threshold uncertainty = 2.5 %) can be reached.

Thus, the uncertainty improvement is: 2.8% – 2.5% = 0.3%.

The average annual emissions are AEm = 120 000 t CO2/year. Therefore, the assumed benefit is 0.003 ·120 000 ·20 € =7 200 €. This is higher than the assumed costs.

 

Guidance document No. 1 concluded that it is therefore not unreasonable to require instrument B installed. It is clear that the whole conception, estimations and final conclusion is actual only assuming 20 € as the allowance price (which is not the case under the current market conditions).

 

Another area where artificial, regulatory-set emission allowances price is established for calculation purposes is the European Commission’s Guidance on the optional application of Article 10c of Directive 2003/87/EC (OJ C 99, 31.3.2011, p. 26).

 

Article 10c of Directive 2003/87/EC allows Member States whose electricity systems meet certain criteria to provide for transitional allocation of emission allowances free of charge to installations for electricity production. The criteria relate to the need to modernise the energy system, and Member States deciding to use this option must in parallel undertake action aimed at securing investments in the energy system, such as upgrades of infrastructure, clean technologies etc., of an amount corresponding to the value of the corresponding emission allocations allocated for free.

 

Annex VI to the above-mentioned Guidance laid down model-based projections of carbon prices in the third trading period which contain price levels between 14.5 € (years 2010 - 2014) and 20 € (2015 – 2020).

 

The unexpected effect of the discrepancy between these ill-designed projections with the  current market prices is that it may occur that it will not at present be advantageous for the electricity generator to spend for instance 25 € on investments in order to gain free emission allowance worth 5 € only.

 

Nevertheless, for investment projects being at the threshold of financial viability, free hand-outs of emission allowances may be an influential driver for ultimate investment decision.

 

 



 

Cap-and-Trade Schemes

Search

TwitterFacebookLinkedin
Copyright © 2009 - 2019 Michal Glowacki. All rights reserved.
The materials contained on this website are for general information purposes only and are subject to the disclaimer